Skip to main content

Value of statistical life year in extreme poverty: a randomized experiment of measurement methods in rural Burkina Faso

Abstract

Background

Value of a Statistical Life Year (VSLY) provides an important economic measure of an individual’s trade-off between health risks and other consumption, and is a widely used policy parameter. Measuring VSLY is complex though, especially in low-income and low-literacy communities.

Methods

Using a large randomized experiment (N = 3027), we study methodological aspects of stated-preference elicitation with payment cards (price lists) in an extreme poverty context. In a 2 × 2 design, we systematically vary whether buying or selling prices are measured, crossed with the range of the payment card.

Results

We find substantial effects of both the pricing method and the list range on elicited VSLY. Estimates of the gross domestic product per capita multiplier for VSLY range from 3.5 to 33.5 depending on the study design. Importantly, all estimates are economically and statistically significantly larger than the current World Health Organization threshold of 3.0 for cost-effectiveness analyses.

Conclusions

Our results inform design choice in VSLY measurements, and provide insight into the potential variability of these measurements and possibly robustness checks.

Peer Review reports

Introduction

The value of a statistical life year (VSLY) provides an economic measure of a decision maker’s personal trade-off between the risk of death and other consumption. It is a core input to policy analysis for risk reductions [1, 2]. Because it is based on how those people affected by some risk value a marginal reduction in the risk, its use avoids undue paternalism. By measuring VSLY for a group of people, averaging their VSLY provides a benchmark that can be used in policy assessments relevant for that group, without the need to measure its value repeatedly for each policy question. That is, the average population (of interest) VSLY forms an important policy input for cost–benefit analysis of risk reduction regulation and investment.

In the health domain, cost-effectiveness analysis similarly assesses the efficiency of health interventions by comparing their monetary costs to the benefits in terms of lives saved. Similar to risk regulation, a population benchmark for those affected is typically applied, in particular measured as a multiple of the relevant per capita gross domestic product (GDP). The World Health Organization defines an intervention as (highly) cost effective if it costs up to three times GDP per live year saved [3, 4], based on expert consensus about the value of economic productivity as well as the additional value of leisure time, market consumption, pure longevity effects, and the value of pain and suffering attributable to disease [5]. It has been argued, however, that the GDP multiple of 3 is not based on any empirical assessment [6] and that, especially in low-income countries, the benefits as perceived by the population exposed to health risk may be much larger than this benchmark [7]. Because extrapolation of VSLY estimates from rich countries with good data availability to low-income countries is difficult, and depends on still poorly understood estimates of income elasticities of VSLY [8], direct measurements in low-income contexts are warranted. Because of the lack of detailed data on job-related mortality risks and the resulting job wage differentials outside the most advanced economies, such measurements must be based on stated-preference techniques (even for many advanced economies).

Unfortunately, very few such measurements in low-income countries exist [9] (see also Robinson and coauthors [2], for a recent survey). In settings of extreme poverty, illiteracy and cultural context often complicate the elicitation of valuations, and this is especially true in the context of complicated life risks [7]. Developing and testing protocols that can be widely applied in low-income countries is therefore of foremost importance. The current study contributes to this research agenda by (1) addressing methodological questions with regard to the pricing of life risks in stated preference surveys, and by (2) providing empirical estimates on VSLY in an extreme poverty region, using a large randomized experiment. In particular, we study the sensitivity of popular choice-based payment card (or price list) methods [10,11,12] to several design aspects. Price list methods are often used to measure individual-level indifference values. In contrast to single-choice methods that potentially provide too little data, and open-ended questions that may be hard to answer, choice-based price list procedures allow participants to weigh costs and benefits and to approach their valuation as prices increase sequentially. However, we argue that these measurements may be sensitive to problems identified in the behavioral decision-making literature, and which have so far exclusively been studied in the context of cost–benefit analyses and VSLY measurements in high-income settings [13].Footnote 1

First, choices may either be framed in terms of willingness-to-pay (WTP) assessments, i.e., as buying price for reduced risk, or alternatively in terms of willingness-to-accept (WTA), i.e., as selling price for accepting increased risk. Often, the choice of WTP or WTA may be dictated by the nature of the risk transformation, e.g., increased health risks due to the placement of a risky factory site (thus WTA). However, for general purpose measurements, it is a-priori unclear which of the two measures is the “correct” way to measure monetary valuations of risk changes [14]. It is common to employ WTP when measuring the economic impact of health-related issues. The Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses by the US environmental protection agency, page 94, suggest that “Willingness to pay to reduce the risk of experiencing an illness is the preferred measure of value for morbidity effects.” [15] However, for many risks to which people become exposed it is not clear that WTP is the obvious choice (e.g., Bishop and coauthors measure of damages due to the BP oil spill based on WTP [16]). Unfortunately, the decision between WTP and WTA is not harmless. A large body of stated-preference literature has documented a substantial discrepancy between valuations based on WTP and WTA, although in theory only a small gap can be rationalized, for instance due to wealth effects. Horowitz and McConnell reviewed roughly 200 studies and found the average ratio of WTA to WTP is about 7.2, with a median of 2.6 [17]. Policy recommendations based on an alternative framing may therefore have strong ramifications for policy decisions.

Second, payment card methods elicit indifference points for risk changes through a list of ordered binary choices for different prices (“price list”). In particular, participants are presented with a set of potential prices, typically in increasing order. For each price, they have to choose whether they are willing to pay this amount for a defined risk reduction (respectively accept the price for a risk increase in WTA). This choice list method allows identifying, at the individual level, the price for which participant is indifferent between buying (respectively selling), and accepting the risk. The price list method is commonly employed in the contingent valuation literature (cf. the paper by Neumann‑Böhme and coauthors [18]). While price lists are a useful decision analytic tool helping respondents to identify their valuation, the selection of the potential prices on the list may influence their decisions. The range and the step size of prices on the list may serve as reference points in the respondents’ assessment of the risk [19,20,21]. Again, within a range of potentially reasonable values, it is not clear what would be the “correct” range and step size of the prices on the list.

Arguing for the importance of more direct measurements of VSLY in low-income countries, Patenaude and coauthors provide a design and method for measuring stated-preference based VSLY in low-income and low-literacy contexts [7]. They carefully tailor the elicitation procedure towards the relevant pool of respondents in low-income settings. The current study builds on the basic paradigm proposed by Patenaude and coauthors to address the effects of the pricing method (WTP or WTA) and the range and step size choices for price-list elicitation of VSLY [7]. In their study in Tanzania, which provides the first measurement of VSLY in sub-Saharan Africa, the authors report a multiple of 4.5 times GDP per capita, significantly larger than the World Health Organization threshold of 3 [7]. We aim to assess the robustness of this finding with respect to variation in the elicitation method. In particular, our design allows us to provide a range of per-capita GDP multiples rather than a single point measurement, that we then compare with the World Health Organization threshold.

Methods

Study area and population

The study area is the Nouna Health and Demographic Surveillance System (HDSS) site located in a rural area in northwestern Burkina Faso [22]. In 2015, the HDSS site covers a population of 107,000 individuals in 15,000 households. All individuals in the HDSS have a unique identifier and Geographic Information Systems (GIS) data are available for all households. Surveillance and research in the Nouna HDSS are conducted by the Centre for Research on Health in Nouna (Centre de Recherche en Santé de Nouna, CRSN).

This paper uses data from the CRSN Heidelberg Aging Study (CHAS), a cross-sectional study investigating the health of older adults in Nouna [23, 24]. CHAS used a two-stage random sample to identify 3998 individuals aged over 40 living in the HDSS site, of whom 3027 participated in the study and completed the questions on VSLY (of the 971 non-participating individuals the largest share moved away or passed away; 196 individuals did not want to participate in the study, and 112 did not give consent; 1 person participated in other parts of the study, but not in the VSLY module). Individuals were interviewed at or near their homes in the local language of their preference.

VSLY measurement

We randomized each CHAS participant to one of the four conditions of our 2 × 2 design for the VSLY question. Because Patenaude and coauthors showed suggestive sex and age differences in VSLY [7], we stratified our randomization by sex and 10-year age brackets. Our elicitation approach closely follows the novel approach and scenario developed for application in rural and very low-income country contexts by Patenaude and coauthors [7]. We ask participants to make a hypothetical monetary judgment of the value of a hypothetical mortality risk reduction or increase (a contingent valuation). The hypothetical nature of the monetary assessment and the involved risks are made clear to the participants. It is also communicated that the monetary amount specified by the participant is a subjective judgment, and that there are no right or wrong answers to the question.

More specifically, we administered a contingent valuation survey to elicit the recurring annual willingness-to-pay (resp. willingness-to-accept) for a permanent 2% reduction (resp. increase) in risk of death from a 5% to a 3% level (from a 3% to a 5% level). The 5% risk represents the typical mortality rate in Burkina Faso, as determined by life tables for 2015.Footnote 2 Risk changes were chosen to allow meaningful communication to our mostly illiterate population (see Fig. 1). Participants were randomized to receive either a WTP or WTA question. We further factorially randomized participants to receive either a small or large range of payment amounts as response options. Both price lists start at zero CFA; the small range of payments had an upper bound of 400,000 CFA (about US$ 1993); the large range of payment had an upper bound of 2 million CFA (about US$ 9966). For comparison, gross domestic product per capita at purchasing power parity in Burkina Faso was US$1,862 in 2017, when the experiment was designed.Footnote 3 The bounds were selected to cover the benchmark case by Patenaude and coauthors [7], which involved an upper bound of TZS10m, which was about US$ 5,000 at the time of the study. Interviewers presented choices for prices in an ascending order to the participants. Both lists contained 20 prices; thus, the average price step in the small-range list was substantially lower than in the large-range list, i.e., the latter led to larger values more quickly. A transcript of the full study material is provided in “Appendix 2”.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Graphical representation of health risks

Interviewers described to respondents two identical communities, which only differ with regard to the probability that each of its members may suffer a sudden and painless death in each year. The different risks in the two communities were illustrated graphically using natural frequencies rather than percentage risks. A matrix showed the number of people who die each year, out of 100 people in the community (see Fig. 1). Respondents were told to imagine being one of these 100 people in one of these communities (lower-risk community for WTA; larger-risk community for WTP), without knowing whether they will be one of the majority of people who live or one of the few who die. Respondents were then asked to specify the annual price they would pay to move to the lower-risk community (WTP), respectively, the payment they require to move to the larger risk community (WTA). Language was intentionally kept neutral and unemotional when describing risks and decisions. This scenario resulted from the development of a feasible design for very low-income contexts by Patenaude et al. [7], making it an appropriate design for our population.

Following Patenaude and coauthors [7], the valuation question asks the individual to consider a recurring annual payment they would be willing to pay, for a persistent risk reduction in their remaining life. Usually, VSLY results from eliciting Value of Statistical Life (VSL) and dividing by expected life years remaining based on the age of the respondent. As in the paper by Patenaude and coauthors [7], our population concerns an extreme poverty context, so life expectancy may not be in line with national life tables. Moreover, individuals make real decisions over value and willingness to pay based on their perceived longevity, not empirical statistical average longevity in a group. This assumes individuals are better judges of their longevity and underlying heath, genetic, and other and risk factors than population average life expectancy. The value we elicit in our paper therefore is mathematically equivalent to VSL divided by undiscounted life expectancy (which is now best practice for VSLY [2]), but where life expectancy is subjectively assessed (recurring payment for life) from each individual. This allows us to calculate the VSLY directly from the questionnaire: Since the observed WTP/WTA is the value of a 2% risk reduction/increase, our VSLY is obtained by multiplying this elicited WTP/WTA measurement by 50 to get to the annual value of a 100% reduction/increase in statistical risk of death [25, 26].

Hypotheses

Based on the behavioral decision making and preference elicitation literature we predict that (1) WTA elicits larger VSLY than WTP [19, 20, 27], and that (2) the large-range (large-step) choice lists elicit larger VSLY than the small-range (small-step) lists [12, 21, 28]. Additionally, we test the hypothesis whether the GDP-per-capita multiple of the VSLY is equal to 3.0 versus larger than 3.0—the World Health Organization (WHO) recommended multiple [7].

Results

In this section, we report the results based on the full sample of N = 2907 individuals who provide valid answers based on the choice-list method. Robustness checks using either trimmed data (removing boundary values), or including non-standard answers (that were not part of the choice list) are provided in “Appendix 1.4 and 1.5” respectively. Overall, surveyors indicated that participants understood the task very well. On a scale from 1 (minimum confidence) to 10 (maximum confidence) that the participant understood the procedures properly, the modal and medium scores were 10 and 9, respectively. We conclude that, despite the complexity of mortality risk pricing, the good understanding of the task indicates that the materials developed by Patenaude and coauthors work well in low-income low-literacy contexts [7]. In “Appendix 1.5,” we give the main result for the restricted sub sample of those participants who were scored with the maximum score on this question.

Demographics

Key demographic information is summarized in Table 1 for each of our four conditions. We have a balanced sample of males and females. Participants are on average 54 years old, 70% of them are currently married and 88% of them have children. On average, they are neither satisfied nor dissatisfied with their health. In the absence of reliable income data, respondents’ household assets are used to construct the wealth index [29]. It is calculated using polychoric principal component analysis, and validated using household expenditure and education data (Poirier and coauthors offer more details regarding the construction of the index specifically for our sample [30]).

Table 1 Socioeconomic and demographic summary statistics

VSLY measurements

Figure 2 presents a compact summary of the observed data, and provides insights regarding the variability of the data. The figure shows that the different methods shift the whole distribution of elicited values, but also affect the shape of the distribution of values. Detailed comparisons of WTP/WTA by condition are shown in Table 2. The upper panel shows the annual indifference payment values (labeled: Price) for a persistent 2% change in mortality risk. The middle panel shows the corresponding VSLYs, and the lower panel shows the resulting GDP-per-capital multiples based on median VSLYs. Elicited valuations differ substantially across the four conditions, with large-range price lists eliciting substantially higher values than small-range price lists, and WTA eliciting larger values than WTP. GDP per capita multiples for median VSLY range from 3.5 for a small-range WTP price list to 33.5 for large-range WTA price list. Compared to the small-range WTP price list benchmark, the change in median VSLY is larger when moving to WTA, while the change in means is larger when moving to the large-range price list. That is, larger ranges in the list lead to more skewed values. All four GDP per capita multiples are significantly larger than the WHO cost effectiveness threshold of 3.0.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Distribution of elicited Value of a Statistical Life Year (VSLY). Notes: Value of a statistical life year (VSLY) as measured in our survey is reported in 2017 purchasing power parity (PPP)-adjusted international dollars. The VSLY in our survey are better represented by a lognormal distribution, so the scale of the x-axis (VSLY) has been log-transformed for ease of visualization and to better reflect the underlying log-normal distribution. The multiples of annual GDP per-capita income in PPP dollars are shown at the top of the x-axis and indicated by dashed vertical lines. They are derived for per capita GDP of $1862 (2017 international dollars). The solid vertical lines in red are the multiples based on median VSLY in each condition

Table 2 Indifference values, VSLYs, and GDP multiple across conditions

We next present a multivariate analysis of the pooled data over all four conditions (raw correlations are shown in Table 4 in “Appendix”). We conduct linear regression analysis of four different models, shown in Table 3. In the simple treatment comparison (Model 1) both large-range and WTA significantly increase VSLY, and there is a significant interaction between the two. Adding wealth (Model 2) does not alter these results, and wealth and VSLY are positively associated, consistent with previous findings. Adding gender, age, and marital status (Model 3), and additionally self-reported health perception and cigarette expenditure as a measure of risk attitude (Model 4) does not qualitatively or quantitatively change the treatment results, although wealth is no longer significantly associated with VSLY after adding the other sociodemographic variables. In models 3 and 4, VSLY is negatively associated with being female; in Model 4 VSLY is negatively associated with higher cigarette expenditures. For US labor market-based data, Viscusi and Hersch also find lower VSLY for women, but no differences between smokers and non-smokers [31]. Table 5 in “Appendix” provides further details on how individual characteristics influence VSLY respectively in each treatment.

Table 3 Determinants of VSLY

An important question in VSLY measurement concerns the validity of the estimates, i.e., that participants comprehend the question and carefully consider their answers. We have provided robustness checks with respect to extreme answers, and have shown that demographics predict valuations in a sensible way. In an additional analysis, we focus on the effect of the choice list method more directly. In “Appendix 1.3”, we replicate the analysis of Table 3, but use the indifference point (i.e., step-level in the choice list) as a dependent variable. Note that, although valuations monotonically increase with the indifference point, each step-level is associated with a larger valuation in the large-range compared to the small-range lists. That is, sensitivity to the economic content of the valuation tasks implies that participants should be indifferent at earlier (lower) steps in the large-range lists. Table 6 shows that this is exactly what we find (while replicating the other patterns observed in Table 3). There is an economically and statistically significant und substantial negative effect of large range on the indifference point. That is, participants react to the economic content of the lists and the scope of values. Still, as we have seen, in terms of valuations they do not adjust their behavior sufficiently, being influenced by the framing of the task.

Discussion

Given the lack of data on VSLY for low income countries, and the difficulty to project estimates from high income countries, more direct evidence from low income settings is warranted [1, 7, 8]. This is especially true in contexts where income increases rapidly due to progress in development [32]. Patenaude and coauthors provide tools for such direct measurement in low income countries with a special focus on sub-Saharan Africa, and argue that current standards for cost-effectiveness assessments may be too low for these regions [7]. Their study focuses on how to implement VSLY elicitation in poor and illiterate populations. We build on their approach to address a problem of broad interest in the context of pricing lives in low-income context, namely the influence of different design aspects on the estimated GDP multiple. Hypotheses are derived from the literature on contingent valuation and behavioral decision making [33,34,35,36]. Our results show that the measurement of VSLY is indeed highly sensitive to the elicitation method: the elicited GDP multiples are found to differ by a factor 10 between the smallest and largest estimate.

Given the large variability of the estimates obtained, applied researchers may ask which approach is the correct one. Unfortunately, there is no easy answer to the question what the correct elicitation design is. For the question of whether WTP or WTA is more appropriate, we may distinguish between paying for improvements, thus WTP, versus accepting deterioration, thus WTA, in health risks [27]. However, Knetsch and coauthors observe that people evaluate outcomes in comparison to an internally construed reference state [37]. If people are not highly aware of mortality risk, their reference state may simply be “to be alive.” Any mortality risk may then be located in the loss domain, and WTA may be the better measure give a reference-dependent utility framework [38]. The lower WTP-based VSLY measures may then result in underinvestment in health interventions. Irrespective of these considerations, the WHO convention of using three times per capita GDP as the benchmark for cost-effectiveness is clearly too low given our estimates for either WTP or WTA.

Price list methods are often used if researchers want to measure individual-level indifference values. Single-choice methods do not provide enough data, and open-ended questions may be very hard to answer, especially for complex issue such as mortality risks. The choice-based price list procedure allows participants to weigh costs and benefits, and to approach their valuation as prices increase sequentially. On the downside, as we have shown, this procedure can be strongly affected by the design of the list. Unfortunately, for the question of how to structure the price list (range, steps), there is no simple answer either. While it is typically impractical to expose respondents to multiple elicitation tasks to identify individual-level sensitivity to the range, randomized variation across respondents, as in our study, is often feasible. The different ranges can be chosen to cover previously reported values for similar contexts. This allows to provide population averages or medians across the pooled sample of methods used, or, as we did in the current study, to provide more direct insights into the possible range of VSLY measures by showing the full range of uncertainty.

We reported median VSLY ranging from 3.5 times to 33.5 times the GDP per capita across four treatment conditions. Restricting our attention to the WTP measurements, we find VSLY ranging from 3.5 to 6.5 in terms of GDP per capita multiples. Our sample characteristics are similar to those of Patenaude and coauthors [7] in terms of proportion of married people, individuals who have children, self-perception of health, but our sample is notably older (on average 15 years older), and we have more male participants. Despite these differences, the WTP-based VSLY value of 4.5 estimated by Patenaude and coauthors falls into the range identified in the current study [7]. Recent WTP estimates from Bangladesh using a titration method instead of price lists show GDP multiples of about 7, thus even somewhat larger than the values found in the current study [9]. Note also that, while our research was conducted pre-COVID-19, we observe that in our regression models, wealth had only modest or no statistically significant influence on elicited VSLY. As such, despite the recent COVID-19 pandemic potentially having an adverse impact on socioeconomic status and wealth in Burkina Faso, we would not expect such shocks to significantly impact the elicited range of VSLY results.

Clearly, both Patenaude and coauthors’ [7] and our sample are characterized by low literacy and extreme poverty. Elicitation of valuations for hypothetical but unpleasant events, as is the case for mortality risk, using counterfactual thinking (risk increases or reductions), is far from trivial and potentially prone to error. Although the results obtained here and in Patenaude and coauthors are not meant to generalize to western populations [7], we may still ask whether results do broadly “make sense,” or whether the setting potentially harmed the elicitation process. To this end, we can compare our results to those of established studies for the USA. Viscusi discusses recent estimates for the US based on labor market data [1]. Such data are not available in most countries, making contingent valuation studies necessary, which then suffer from the methodological issues that were the focus of the current study. Viscusi reports recent estimates of VSLY of US$ 411,000 for the US (in 2015 dollars [25]). With a GDP per capita of about US$ 57,000 in 2015, the resulting GDP-per-capita multiple would be in range of 7.21 for the USA. For an older cohort of people older than 50, a maximum value of 9.56 for the GDP multiple at age 54 can be calculated from the Aldy and Viscusi’s data [1]. A recent review of 133 estimates in the literature on VSLY found a median value of €164,000, mapping on a GDP multiple of more than 6 [39]. Thus, while the VSLY values that we elicited look large, they certainly fall within the range of values observed in other studies using different methodology and different populations. As discussed by Viscusi, people at different income levels face different trade-offs [1]. VSLYs in low-income countries may be lower than in the USA in absolute terms, but may not necessarily be lower in relative terms.

The data suggest that there may be many cost-effective interventions in low-income context which are not considered under the current policy using the threshold of three times GDP. Efficiency does not imply affordability. As the World Health Organization argues, these interventions provide good value: If low-income countries cannot afford them, the international community should find ways to support their efforts [3].

Conclusions

For policy purposes, the important insight is that even the lowest GDP multiples elicited in our study are significantly larger than the WHO recommendation of three times the local annual income, as a measure of the benefit of health interventions. Given the sensitivity of VSLY measurement to the method employed, and the important role the results play in cost-effectiveness assessments, we recommend to employ different elicitation methods to obtain a range of VSLY when measuring it for policy purposes. We focused on range effects and WTP versus WTA. Andersson and Svensson point to additional features that may become important, notably the size of the assessed risk change [40]. If the risk change is not determined by substantial factors of the policy question at hand, it may be useful to also consider that dimension. With more studies including multiple designs, meta-analyses will be able to identify the effects of different design features to allow for more robust estimates [19, 27].

Availability of data and material

Data are not publicly available as consent was not given by participants for data to be shared openly. This is in part because entire age cohorts of some villages are included in the dataset, potentially allowing for deductive disclosure with sufficient local information. For this reason, anonymized data is available from CHAS study data controllers only following signature of a data use agreement restricting onward transmission. Anyone wishing to replicate the analyses presented, or conduct further collaborative analyses using CHAS (which are welcomed and considered based on a letter of intent), should contact Dr. Guy Harling (g.harling@ucl.ac.uk) in the first instance.

Notes

  1. Payment scales are closely related to payment cards, having the respondents choose one price from a list of prices, rather than sequentially presenting choices between accepting and not accepting each price. The therefore potentially suffer from similar problems as those discussed in the current study for payment cards.

  2. See the World Health Organization webpage [41].

  3. See World Bank Data [42].

Abbreviations

CERS:

Comité d’Ethique pour la Recherche en Santé

CFA:

Franc of the Financial Community of Africa

CHAS:

CRSN Heidelberg Aging Study

CIE:

Institutional Ethics Committee

CRSN:

Centre de Recherche en Santé de Nouna

GDP:

Gross domestic product

GIS:

Geographic information system

HDSS:

Health and demographic surveillance system

OLS:

Ordinary least squares

PPP:

Purchasing power parity

VSL:

Value of statistical life

VSLY:

Value of statistical life year

WHO:

World Health Organization

WTA:

Willingness-to-accept

WTP:

Willingness-to-pay

References

  1. Viscusi W. Pricing lives. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2018.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  2. Robinson LA, Hammitt JK, Jamison DT, Walker DG. Conducting benefit-cost analysis in low-and middle-income countries: introduction to the special issue. J Benefit-Cost Anal. 2019;10:1–14.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  3. World Health Organisation. The world health report: reducing risks, promoting healthy life. Geneva: WHO; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Cameron D, Ubels J, Norström F. On what basis are medical cost-effectiveness thresholds set? Clashing opinions and an absence of data: a systematic review. Glob Health Action. 2018;11:1447828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Sachs JD. Macroeconomics and health: investing in health for economic development: report of the commission on macroeconomics and health. Nat. Med. Geneva PP - Geneva: World Health Organization; 2001. p. 1–200.

  6. Robinson LA, Hammitt JK, Chang AY, Resch S. Understanding and improving the one and three times GDP per capita cost-effectiveness thresholds. Health Policy Plan. 2017;32:141–5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Patenaude BN, Semali I, Killewo J, Bärnighausen T. The value of a statistical life-year in Sub-Saharan Africa: evidence from a large population-based survey in Tanzania. Value Health Reg Issues. 2019;19:151–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Hammitt JK, Robinson LA. The income elasticity of the value per statistical life: transferring estimates between high and low income populations. J Benefit-Cost Anal. 2011;2:1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Odihi D, De Broucker G, Hasan Z, Ahmed S, Constenla D, Uddin J, et al. Contingent valuation: a pilot study for eliciting willingness to pay for a reduction in mortality from vaccine-preventable illnesses for children and adults in Bangladesh. Value Heal Reg Issues. 2021;24:67–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Bärnighausen T, Liu Y, Zhang X, Sauerborn R. Willingness to pay for social health insurance among informal sector workers in Wuhan, China: a contingent valuation study. BMC Health Serv Res. 2007;7:1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Smith RD. It’s not just what you do, it’s the way that you do it: the effect of different payment card formats and survey administration on willingness to pay for health gain. Health Econ. 2006;15:281–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Soeteman L, van Exel J, Bobinac A. The impact of the design of payment scales on the willingness to pay for health gains. Eur J Heal Econ. 2017;18:743–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Johnston RJ, Boyle KJ, Adamowicz W, Bennett J, Brouwer R, Cameron TA, et al. Contemporary guidance for stated preference studies. J Assoc Environ Resour Econ. 2017;4:319–405.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Henderson A. Consumer’s surplus and the compensating variation. Rev Econ Stud. 1941;8:117–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Us EPA. Guidelines for preparing economic analyses. EPA 240-R-00-003. Washington, DC: US Environmental Protection Agency; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Bishop RC, Boyle KJ, Carson RT, Chapman D, Hanemann WM, Kanninen B, et al. Putting a value on injuries to natural assets: the BP oil spill. Science (80- ). 2017;356:253–4.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  17. Horowitz JK, McConnell KE. A review of WTA/WTP studies. J Environ Econ Manag. 2002;44:426–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Neumann-Böhme S, Lipman SA, Brouwer WBF, Attema AE. Trust me; I know what I am doing investigating the effect of choice list elicitation and domain-relevant training on preference reversals in decision making for others. Eur J Health Econ. 2021;22:679–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Dolan P, Metcalfe R, Munro V, Christensen MC. Valuing lives and life years: anomalies, implications, and an alternative. Health Econ Policy Law. 2008;3:277–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Kniesner TJ. Behavioral economics and the value of a statistical life. J Risk Uncertain. 2019;58:207–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Whynes DK, Wolstenholme JL, Frew E. Evidence of range bias in contingent valuation payment scales. Health Econ. 2004;13:183–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Sié A, Louis V, Gbangou A, Müller O, Niamba L, Stieglbauer G, et al. The health and demographic surveillance system (HDSS) in Nouna, Burkina Faso, 1993–2007. Glob Health Action. 2010;3:5284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Witham MD, Davies JI, Bärnighausen T, Bountogo M, Manne-Goehler J, Payne CF, et al. Frailty and physical performance in the context of extreme poverty: a population-based study of older adults in rural Burkina Faso. Wellcome Open Res. 2019;4:135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Odland ML, Payne C, Witham MD, Siedner MJ, Bärnighausen T, Bountogo M, et al. Epidemiology of multimorbidity in conditions of extreme poverty: a population-based study of older adults in rural Burkina Faso. BMJ Glob Health. 2020;5:e002096.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Aldy JE, Viscusi WK. Age differences in the value of statistical life: revealed preference evidence. Rev Environ Econ Policy. 2007;1:241–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Bateman IJ. Valid value estimates and value estimate validation: better methods and better testing for stated preference research. In: Bennett J, editor. The international handbook on non-market environmental valuation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing; 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Robinson LA, Hammitt JK. Skills of the trade: valuing health risk reductions in benefit-cost analysis. J Benefit-Cost Anal. 2013;4:107–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Bohm P, Lindén J, Sonnegård J. Eliciting reservation prices: Becker–DeGroot–Marschak mechanisms vs. markets. Econ J. 1997;107:1079–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Filmer D, Pritchett LH. Estimating wealth effects without expenditure data-or tears: an application to educational enrollments in states of India. Demography. 2001;38:115–32.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  30. Poirier MJP, Bärnighausen T, Harling G, Sié A, Grépin KA. Is the lack of smartphone data skewing wealth indices in low-income settings? Popul Health Metr. 2021;19:4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Viscusi WK, Hersch J. The mortality cost to smokers. J Health Econ. 2008;27:943–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Hammitt JK, Geng F, Guo X, Nielsen CP. Valuing mortality risk in China: comparing stated-preference estimates from 2005 and 2016. J Risk Uncertain. 2019;58:167–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Hammack J, Brown GM. Waterfowl and wetlands: toward bioeconomic analysis. London: Routledge; 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Samuelson W, Zeckhauser R. Status quo bias in decision making. J Risk Uncertain. 1988;1:7–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Kachelmeier SJ, Shehata M. Examining risk preferences under high monetary incentives: experimental evidence from the People ’ s Republic of China. Am Econ Rev. 1992;82:1120–41.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Rabin M. Psychology and economics. J Econ Lit. 1998;36:11–46.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Knetsch JL, Riyanto YE, Zong J. Gain and loss domains and the choice of welfare measure of positive and negative changes. J Benefit-Cost Anal. 2012;3:1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Knetsch JL. Values of gains and losses: reference states and choice of measure. Environ Resour Econ. 2010;46:179–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Schlander M, Schwarz O, Hernández D, Schaefer R. New estimates of the willingness-to-pay for a statistical life year: a systematic review of the empirical economic literature. Value Health. 2018;21:S111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Andersson H, Svensson M. Scale sensitivity and question order in the contingent valuation method. J Environ Plan Manag. 2014;57:1746–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. World Health Organization. Global Health Observatory data repository. https://apps.who.int/gho/data/view.main.LT61990?lang=en. Accessed 8 Oct 2021.

  42. World Bank Open Data. GDP per capita, PPP (current international $). https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.PP.CD?year_high_desc=false. Accessed 8 Oct 2021

Download references

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

Funding

Open Access funding enabled and organized by Projekt DEAL. Till Bärnighausen was supported by the Alexander von Humboldt Foundation through the Alexander von Humboldt Professor award, funded by the Federal Ministry of Education and Research; the German Research Foundation; the Wellcome Trust; and from NICHD of NIH (R01-HD084233), NIA of NIH (P01-AG041710), NIAID of NIH (R01-AI124389 and R01-AI112339) as well as FIC of NIH (D43-TW009775). Guy Harling is supported by a fellowship from the Royal Society and the Wellcome Trust [210479/Z/18/Z]. The funding bodies had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analysis, and interpretation of data, or in writing the manuscript. Christian König-Kersting was supported by grant F6309 of the Austrian Science Fund FWF.This research was funded in whole, or in part, by the Wellcome Trust [Grant Number 210479/Z/18/Z]. For the purpose of open access, the author has applied a CC BY public copyright license to any Author Accepted Manuscript version arising from this submission.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

ST and TB developed the research question. ST, CK and BP designed the study materials. GH and AS prepared IRB request and implemented the data collection in the field. ST and YX analyzed the data. ST and YX wrote the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefan T. Trautmann.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Ethical approval for CHAS was obtained from Ethics Commission I of the medical faculty Heidelberg (S-120/2018), the Burkina Faso Comité d’Ethique pour la Recherche en Santé (CERS) in Ouagadougou (2018-4-045) and the Institutional Ethics Committee (CIE) of the CRSN (2018-04). Oral assent was sought from village elders. Written informed consent was obtained from each participant; in cases of illiteracy, a literate witness assisted.

Consent to publication

Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: additional analyses

Correlation of variables

Table 4 provides the raw correlation of the control variables and VSLY.

Table 4 Correlation tables of key variables

VSLY determinants by treatment

It may be of interest how individual characteristics influence valuations in different treatments. Table 5 below summarizes these results.

Table 5 Effect of demographics by treatment

Analysis of the selected row on the price list

Instead of analyzing the monetary amount (VSLY) as in the main text, here we analyze whether and how the treatment variables affect the indifference-row emerging from the choice list procedure for each respondent. For WTP, the selected row indicates the maximum annual fee a respondent is willing to pay to live in a lower-risk community. For WTA, the selected row indicates the minimum annual compensation a respondent demands for living in a higher-risk community (Table 6).

Table 6 Determinants of the selected row

Trimmed data (removing 0 s and max values)

We examine the results for VSLY with extreme values have been removed. We exclude all respondents who indicate 0 and those who indicated the largest value on the price list, because these respondents might not wish to value their lives in terms of money or are limited by the boundaries. Table 7 shows that the results in the main text are largely unaffected.

Table 7 Indifference values, VSLYs, and GDP multiple across conditions

Non-standard answers and task comprehension

Tables 8 and 9 report the key tables and regressions using the full sample, including additional 120 participants who gave non-standard answers. These participants directly gave a WTP or WTA that was not part of the price list. We find that results reported in the main text are qualitatively unaffected when including these respondents.

Table 8 Indifference values, VSLYs, and GDP multiple across conditions
Table 9 Determinants of VSLY

Table 10 reports the main analyses of Table 2 for only those participants who were scored with maximum confidence level that they understood the question properly. The table shows that the main result replicates for this subsample of participants, with strong differences between conditions as for the full sample. All conditions except WTP_small reveal GDP multiples significantly larger than 3.

Table 10 Indifference values, VSLYs, and GDP multiple across conditions (maximum confidence level that participant fully understood the question)

Appendix 2: transcript of Study materials

Variant 1 (small range, wtp)

Let me briefly explain the way I would like us to approach the following question. We have come up with hypothetical situations that we would like you to imagine yourself in. You will be faced with difficult decisions that involve the risk of death. We are not in any way suggesting that by imagining yourself in these situations, you will experience what we present you with. We are also most certainly not wishing illness or even death upon you. We simply want to find out what choices people make when they find themselves in such difficult situations. Please simply ask yourself: what would I do if I was to find myself in such a situation? There are no right or wrong answers to the question we ask. Does that make sense?

Q1. I would now ask you to imagine the following two situations. In the first situation, you live in a community in which 5 out of 100 people die every year: you are one of these 100 people, thus the chance that you will die is 5 out of 100. In the second situation, you live in a community in which 3 out of 100 people die every year: thus the chance that you will die is 3 out of 100. In both situations the death is sudden and painless. You should also imagine that except for the risk of death, everything in your life is the same in the two communities. The picture below helps to illustrate the risk. For each 100 people, the crossed-out figures will die. Imagine yourself to be one of the 100 people, but you do not yet know which one. Thus, you might be one of those who die, or one of those who do not die.

figure a

Imagine that you live in a community where the risk of death is 5 out of 100 people each year. You can now pay a certain amount of money each year to instead live in a community with a risk of death of 3 out of 100 people per year. Here we would like to know what the maximum annual fee in CFA is that you would be willing to reduce your risk of death from 5 out of 100 people to a risk of death of 3 out of 100 people. In other words, what would be the maximum annual fee in CFA that you would be willing to pay, to live in a community where the risk of death is 3 out of 100 people rather than 5 out of 100 people.

Please be sure to take into account what you can actually afford to pay, and not if you had unlimited money. Please check the box for the maximum amount of CFA below.

[Start from low amounts going up, asking “Would you pay no more than X, or more?”. If respondent indicates that his/her value is in between two values in the list, tick the two value bracketing the value indicated by respondent.]

 

I am willing to pay this annual fee to reduce my risk of death from 5 out of 100 to 3 out of 100 per year

Amount (annual, CFA fr)

Check maximum value

0

O

1000

O

2500

O

5000

O

10,000

O

15,000

O

20,000

O

25,000

O

30,000

O

35,000

O

40,000

O

45,000

O

50,000

O

60,000

O

70,000

O

80,000

O

100,000

O

150,000

O

200,000

O

400,000

O

Q2. How confident are you that the respondent understood the questions in this section? Please indicate your impression of the respondent’s level of understanding on a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 = the respondent did not understand the question at all, and 10 = the respondent fully understood the question. Please place a circle around the number.

Did not understand the question at all

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Fully understood the question

Variant 2 (large range, wtp)

Let me briefly explain the way I would like us to approach the following question. We have come up with hypothetical situations that we would like you to imagine yourself in. You will be faced with difficult decisions that involve the risk of death. We are not in any way suggesting that by imagining yourself in these situations, you will experience what we present you with. We are also most certainly not wishing illness or even death upon you. We simply want to find out what choices people make when they find themselves in such difficult situations. Please simply ask yourself: what would I do if I was to find myself in such a situation? There are no right or wrong answers to the question we ask. Does that make sense?

Q1. I would now ask you to imagine the following two situations. In the first situation, you live in a community in which 5 out of 100 people die every year: you are one of these 100 people, thus the chance that you will die is 5 out of 100. In the second situation, you live in a community in which 3 out of 100 people die every year: thus the chance that you will die is 3 out of 100. In both situations the death is sudden and painless. You should also imagine that except for the risk of death, everything in your life is the same in the two communities. The picture below helps to illustrate the risk. For each 100 people, the crossed-out figures will die. Imagine yourself to be one of the 100 people, but you do not yet know which one. Thus, you might be one of those who die, or one of those who do not die.

figure b

Imagine that you live in a community where the risk of death is 5 out of 100 people each year. You can now pay a certain amount of money each year to instead live in a community with a risk of death of 3 out of 100 people per year. Here we would like to know what the maximum annual fee in CFA is that you would be willing to reduce your risk of death from 5 out of 100 people to a risk of death of 3 out of 100 people. In other words, what would be the maximum annual fee in CFA that you would be willing to pay, to live in a community where the risk of death is 3 out of 100 people rather than 5 out of 100 people.

Please be sure to take into account what you can actually afford to pay, and not if you had unlimited money. Please check the box for the maximum amount of CFA below.

[Start from low amounts going up, asking “Would you pay no more than X, or more?”. If respondent indicates that his/her value is in between two values in the list, tick the two value bracketing the value indicated by respondent.]

 

I am willing to pay this annual fee to reduce my risk of death from 5 out of 100 to 3 out of 100 per year

Amount (annual, CFA fr)

Check maximum value

0

O

5000

O

10,000

O

25,000

O

50,000

O

100,000

O

150,000

O

200,000

O

250,000

O

300,000

O

400,000

O

500,000

O

600,000

O

700,000

O

800,000

O

1,000,000

O

1,200,000

O

1,400,000

O

1,700,000

O

2,000,000

O

Q2. How confident are you that the respondent understood the questions in this section? Please indicate your impression of the respondent’s level of understanding on a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 = the respondent did not understand the question at all, and 10 = the respondent fully understood the question. Please place a circle around the number.

Did not understand the question at all

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Fully understood the question

Variant 3 (small range, WTA)

Let me briefly explain the way I would like us to approach the following question. We have come up with hypothetical situations that we would like you to imagine yourself in. You will be faced with difficult decisions that involve the risk of death. We are not in any way suggesting that by imagining yourself in these situations, you will experience what we present you with. We are also most certainly not wishing illness or even death upon you. We simply want to find out what choices people make when they find themselves in such difficult situations. Please simply ask yourself: what would I do if I was to find myself in such a situation? There are no right or wrong answers to the question we ask. Does that make sense?

Q1. I would now ask you to imagine the following two situations. In the first situation, you live in a community in which 3 out of 100 people die every year: you are one of these 100 people, thus the chance that you will die is 3 out of 100. In the second situation, you live in a community in which 5 out of 100 people die every year: thus the chance that you will die is 5 out of 100. In both situations the death is sudden and painless. You should also imagine that except for the risk of death, everything in your life is the same in the two communities. The picture below helps to illustrate the risk. For each 100 people, the crossed-out figures will die. Imagine yourself to be one of the 100 people, but you do not yet know which one. Thus, you might be one of those who die, or one of those who do not die.

figure c

Imagine that you live in a community where the risk of death is 3 out of 100 people each year. You can now receive a certain amount of money each year if you accept to instead live in a community with a risk of death of 5 out of 100 people per year. Here we would like to know what the minimum annual fee in CFA is that you would require as compensation to accept your risk of death to increase from 3 out of 100 people to a risk of death of 5 out of 100 people. In other words, what would be the minimum annual fee in CFA that you would require as compensation, to accept living in a community where the risk of death is 5 out of 100 people rather than 3 out of 100 people.

Please be sure to think about the absolute minimum compensation you would require, which may not be the amount someone else is able or willing to compensate you. That is, we want to know what your personal acceptable minimum is, irrespective of what you believe could be paid by someone. Please check the box for the minimum amount of CFA below.

[Start from low amounts going up, asking “Would accept the risk increase for X, or do you require more?” If respondent indicates that his/her value is in between two values in the list, tick the two value bracketing the value indicated by respondent.]

 

I require at least this annual fee to accept an increase in my risk of death from 3 out of 100 to 5 out of 100 per year

Amount (annual, CFA fr)

Check minimum value

0

O

1000

O

2500

O

5000

O

10,000

O

15,000

O

20,000

O

25,000

O

30,000

O

35,000

O

40,000

O

45,000

O

50,000

O

60,000

O

70,000

O

80,000

O

100,000

O

150,000

O

200,000

O

400,000

O

Q2. How confident are you that the respondent understood the questions in this section? Please indicate your impression of the respondent’s level of understanding on a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 = the respondent did not understand the question at all, and 10 = the respondent fully understood the question. Please place a circle around the number.

Did not understand the question at all

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Fully understood the question

Variant 4 (large range, wta)

Let me briefly explain the way I would like us to approach the following question. We have come up with hypothetical situations that we would like you to imagine yourself in. You will be faced with difficult decisions that involve the risk of death. We are not in any way suggesting that by imagining yourself in these situations, you will experience what we present you with. We are also most certainly not wishing illness or even death upon you. We simply want to find out what choices people make when they find themselves in such difficult situations. Please simply ask yourself: what would I do if I was to find myself in such a situation? There are no right or wrong answers to the question we ask. Does that make sense?

Q1. I would now ask you to imagine the following two situations. In the first situation, you live in a community in which 3 out of 100 people die every year: you are one of these 100 people, thus the chance that you will die is 3 out of 100. In the second situation, you live in a community in which 5 out of 100 people die every year: thus the chance that you will die is 5 out of 100. In both situations the death is sudden and painless. You should also imagine that except for the risk of death, everything in your life is the same in the two communities. The picture below helps to illustrate the risk. For each 100 people, the crossed-out figures will die. Imagine yourself to be one of the 100 people, but you do not yet know which one. Thus, you might be one of those who die, or one of those who do not die.

figure d

Imagine that you live in a community where the risk of death is 3 out of 100 people each year. You can now receive a certain amount of money each year if you accept to instead live in a community with a risk of death of 5 out of 100 people per year. Here we would like to know what the minimum annual fee in CFA is that you would require as compensation to accept your risk of death to increase from 3 out of 100 people to a risk of death of 5 out of 100 people. In other words, what would be the minimum annual fee in CFA that you would require as compensation, to accept living in a community where the risk of death is 5 out of 100 people rather than 3 out of 100 people.

Please be sure to think about the absolute minimum compensation you would require, which may not be the amount someone else is able or willing to compensate you. That is, we want to know what your personal acceptable minimum is, irrespective of what you believe could be paid by someone. Please check the box for the minimum amount of CFA below.

[Start from low amounts going up, asking “Would accept the risk increase for X, or do you require more?” If respondent indicates that his/her value is in between two values in the list, tick the two value bracketing the value indicated by respondent.]

 

I require at least this annual fee to accept an increase in my risk of death from 3 out of 100 to 5 out of 100 per year

Amount (annual, CFA fr)

Check minimum value

0

O

5000

O

10,000

O

25,000

O

50,000

O

100,000

O

150,000

O

200,000

O

250,000

O

300,000

O

400,000

O

500,000

O

600,000

O

700,000

O

800,000

O

1,000,000

O

1,200,000

O

1,400,000

O

1,700,000

O

2,000,000

O

Q2. How confident are you that the respondent understood the questions in this section? Please indicate your impression of the respondent’s level of understanding on a scale from 1 to 10, where 1 = the respondent did not understand the question at all, and 10 = the respondent fully understood the question. Please place a circle around the number.

Did not understand the question at all

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Fully understood the question

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/. The Creative Commons Public Domain Dedication waiver (http://creativecommons.org/publicdomain/zero/1.0/) applies to the data made available in this article, unless otherwise stated in a credit line to the data.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Trautmann, S.T., Xu, Y., König-Kersting, C. et al. Value of statistical life year in extreme poverty: a randomized experiment of measurement methods in rural Burkina Faso. Popul Health Metrics 19, 45 (2021). https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.1186/s12963-021-00275-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.1186/s12963-021-00275-y

Keywords